By Cristian Alonso, Siddharth Kothari, and Sidra Rehman
NEW technologies like artificial intelligence, machine learning, robotics, big data, and networks are not only expected to revolutionize production processes, but they could also have a major impact on developing economies.
The opportunities and potential sources of growth that, for example, the United States and China enjoyed during their early stages of economic development are remarkably different from what Cambodia and Tanzania are facing in today’s world.
Our recent staff research finds that new technology risks widening the gap between rich and poor countries by shifting more investment to advanced economies where automation is already established.
This could in turn have negative consequences for jobs in developing countries by threatening to replace rather than complement their growing labour force, which has traditionally provided an advantage to less developed economies.
To prevent this growing divergence, policymakers in developing economies will need to take actions to raise productivity and improve skills among workers.
Results from a model
Our model looks at two countries – one advanced and the other developing – that both produce goods using three factors of production: labour, capital, and robots.
We interpret “robots” broadly, to encompass the whole range of new technologies mentioned above. Our main assumption is that robots substitute for workers.
The “artificial intelligence revolution” in our framework is an increase in the productivity of robots.
We find that divergence between developing and advanced economies can occur along three distinct channels: share-in production, investment flows, and terms-of-trade.
Share-in-production: Advanced economies have higher wages because total factor productivity is higher. These higher wages induce firms in advanced economies to use robots more intensively to begin with, especially when robots easily substitute for workers. Then, when robot productivity rises, the advanced economy will benefit more in the long run. This divergence grows larger, the more robots substitute for workers.
Investment flows: The increase in productivity of robots fuels strong demand to invest in robots and traditional capital (which is assumed to be complementary to robots and labour). This demand is larger in advanced economies due to robots being used more intensively there. As a result, investment gets diverted from developing countries to finance this capital and robot accumulation in advanced economies, thus resulting in a transitional decline in gross domestic product (GDP) in the developing country.
Terms-of-trade: A developing economy will likely specialize in sectors that rely more on unskilled labour compared to an advanced economy. Assuming robots replace unskilled labour but complement skilled workers, a permanent decline in the terms of trade in the developing region may emerge after the robot revolution. This is because robots will disproportionately displace unskilled workers, reducing their relative wages and lowering the price of the good that uses unskilled labour more intensively. The drop in relative price of its main output, in turn, acts as a further negative shock, reducing the incentive to invest and potentially leading to a fall not just in relative but in absolute GDP.
Robots and wages
Our results critically depend on whether robots indeed substitute for workers. While it may be too early to predict the extent of this substitution in the future, we find suggestive evidence that this is the case. In particular, we find that higher wages coincide with significantly higher use of robots, consistent with the idea that firms substitute away from workers and towards robots in response to higher labour costs.
Implications
Improvements in the productivity of robots drive divergence between advanced and developing countries if robots substitute easily for workers. In addition, those improvements tend to increase incomes and income inequality, at least during the transition and possibly in the long run for some groups of workers, in both advanced and developing economies.
Given the fast pace of the robot revolution, developing countries need to invest in raising aggregate productivity and skill levels more urgently than ever before, so that their labour force is complemented rather than substituted by robots.
In our model, increases in total factor productivity—which account for the many institutional and other fundamental differences between developing and advanced countries not captured by labour and capital inputs—are especially beneficial as they incentivize more robots and physical capital accumulation.
Our findings also underscore the importance of human capital accumulation to prevent divergence and point to potentially different growth dynamics among developing economies with different skill levels.
The landscape is likely going to be much more challenging for developing countries which have hoped for high dividends from a much-anticipated demographic transition. The growing youth population in developing countries was hailed by policymakers as possibly a big chance to benefit from a transition of jobs from China as a result of its graduating middle-income status.
Our findings also show that robots may steal these jobs. Policymakers should act to mitigate those risks. Especially in the face of these new technologically-driven pressures, a drastic shift to rapidly improve productivity gains and invest in education and skills development will capitalize on the much-anticipated demographic transition. – Dec 3, 2020
Cristian Alonso is an economist in the IMF’s Fiscal Affairs Department, Siddharth Kothari is an economist in the IMF’s Asia and Pacific Department and Sidra Rehman is an economist in the IMF’s Middle East and Central Asia Department
The views expressed are those of the author(s) and do not necessarily represent the views of the IMF and its Executive Board or Focus Malaysia.